Showing posts with label Welfare. Show all posts
Showing posts with label Welfare. Show all posts

Tuesday, December 5, 2023

Housing Assistance Agencies Currently Operating in Waukegan, Illinois

Housing Assistance Agencies Currently Operating in Waukegan, Illinois

Alexian Brothers Housing & Health Alliance – The Harbor
- Address: 826 North Ave., Waukegan
- Phone Number: 847-782-8015

Catholic Charities of the Archdiocese of Chicago
- Address: 671 S. Lewis Ave., Waukegan
- Phone Number: 847-782-4000

Community Action Partnership of Lake County
- Address: 2424 Washington St., Waukegan
- 847-249-4330

El Puente Latino (food bank, may have housing)
- Address: 2415 Butrick St., Waukegan
- Phone Number: 847-597-3051

Family First Center of Lake County
- Address: 2504 Washington St., Suite 300G, Waukegan &/or 2408 29th St., Waukegan
- Phone Number: 224-789-7763

Habitat for Humanity – Lake County
- Address: 315 N. M.L.K. Jr. Ave., Waukegan
- Phone Number: 847-623-1020

Love, Inc. – Lake County
- Address: 339 Lakewood Ave.
- Phone Number: 847-782-8630

House of Peace
- Address: 671 S. Lewis Ave., Waukegan
- 224 430-4977

Mary’s Mission
- Address: 642 S. M.L.K. Jr. Ave. , Waukegan
- Phone Number: 847-623-2136

One Hope United – Rebound
- Address: N. Lewis Ave., Waukegan
- Phone Number: 847-662-0945

P.A.D.S. Lake County – P.A.D.S. Office (homeless outreach service)
- Address: 1800 Grand Ave., Waukegan
- Phone Number: 847-869-4357

P.A.D.S. Lake County – Waukegan Public Library (homeless outreach service)
- Address: 18 N. County St., Waukegan
- Phone Number: 847-623-2041

Salvation Army – Waukegan Corps Community Center
- Address: Green Bay Rd, Waukegan
- Phone Number: 847-336-1880

Staben House (homeless shelter)
- Address: 3000 Grand Ave., Waukegan &/or 422 South Avenue, Waukegan
- Phone Number: 847-244-9944 or 847-244-0805

Waukegan Main Street
- Address: 214 Washington St., Waukegan
- Phone Number: 847-623-6650

Y.W.C.A. – Lake County
- Address: 1537 S. Waukegan Rd., Waukegan
- Phone Number: 847-662-4247




Might Not Provide Housing (Call to Find Out)

Christian Fellowship Church
- Address: 621 Belvidere St.
- Phone Number: 847-336-1815

Greater Faith Church – Baptist
- Address: 565 Powell Ave.
- Phone Number: 847-244-4400)

Liberty Temple Full Gospel Church
- Address: 711 8th St.
- Phone Number: 847-662-3182)

Mt. Moriah Christian Center
- Address: 524 10th St.
- Phone Number: 847-662-5683

North Point Community Christian Church
- Address: 900 Lewis Ave.
- Phone Number: 847-746-5522

Truth Youth & Family Counseling Services
- Address: 2504 Washington St.
- Phone Number: 224-489-7773

Waukegan Adult Rehabilitation Center
- Address: 431 S. Genesee St.
- Phone Number: 847-662-7730








Written and Published on December 5th, 2023

Thursday, August 5, 2021

Which Needs Do Different Political Ideologies Consider to Be Basic Government Services?

      The infographic below is a political spectrum that shows six different political ideologies, and their views on which human needs should be considered basic or essential services that government should provide.



Image created by the author of this blog, Joe Kopsick

Click on image, and open in new tab and/or window,
or download, in order to view in full resolution




     One of the things that inspired me to create the image above, was the image below, which I have seen in libertarian discussion groups online.
     This image was created to help explain the perspectives of the libertarian minarchists (advocates of the minimum amount of government necessary), and voluntaryists (libertarians who want to abolish the state as well as all coercive forms of taxation and government).





Image not created by the author of this blog





     Here is another version of the image above, which was created in order to illustrate the importance of embracing voluntaryism, rejecting the violence that the state legitimizes, and rejecting the force that the state authorizes (in order to apply the law and collect taxes, etc.).




Image not created by the author of this blog





     I urge my readers to compare and contrast the three images above, with images depicting Thomas Maslow's "hierarchy of needs".
     Those who do so will notice that the services deemed basic or essential by the progressives and communists, lines up almost perfectly with the set of basic human needs which comprise the lowest level or levels of Maslow's hierarchy (i.e., those corresponding to maintaining the health, nutrition, and well-being of the human body).
     Also, the services deemed basic by the communitarians and socialists, loosely corresponds with the human needs found in the center of Maslow's hierarchy (i.e., those that relate to belonging).





Image not created by the author of this blog









Original image created on August 5th, 2021

Article published on August 5th, 2021

Saturday, July 27, 2019

When the Law Does the Opposite of What it Intends to Do: One Hundred Twelve Theses on Government Failure (Incomplete)

When the Law Does the Opposite of What it Intends to Do:
One Hundred Twelve Theses on Government Failure



First Table of Contents

Part 1: Introduction (Including Eighteen Bad Basic Laws of Government)

I.
First Introduction: Government Failure
II. Second Introduction: Five Reasons Why We Shouldn't Trust the Government
III. Three Clauses That Enable Legislative Action, But Are Used to Excuse Government Overreach
IV. Six Laws with Deceptive Names
V. Eight Self-Defeating Amendments (Plus the Draft)


Part 2: The Wars on Terror, Drugs, and Poverty (Including Seventy Bad Laws)

VI. The War on Terror: Fourteen Laws That Fail to Protect People from War, Terrorism, and Violent Crime
VII. The Wars on Drugs and Our Health: Twenty-One Laws That Failed to Achieve Affordable Health Care, Failed to Ensure the Legal Sale of Safe Drugs, or Failed to Protect the Environment
VIII. The War on Poverty, Part 1: Eleven Laws That Fail to Protect Workers' Rights and the Interests of Labor Unions
IX. The War on Poverty, Part 2: Seven Laws That Intended to Protect Minorities and/or Property, But Failed
X. The War on Poverty, Part 3: Six Budgetary and Monetary Policies That Have Led to Economic Ruin
XI. The War on Poverty, Part 4: Ten Laws That Intended to Make the Markets Free, But Rigged Them Instead


Part 3: Other Topics (Including Twenty-Five Bad Laws, and a Conclusion)

XII. Five Failed Laws and Policies Related to Insurance
XIII. Four Laws That Tried to Prevent Frivolous Lawsuits, But Go Too Far
XIV. Five Laws That Tried to Protect the Rights or Safety of Women and Homosexuals, But Failed
XV. Eight Laws and Programs That Fail to Protect Children
XVI. Three More Terrible Laws
XVII. Conclusion: New Laws Don't Work





Second Table of Contents





Part 1: Introduction (Including Eighteen Bad Basic Laws of Government)



I. 
First Introduction: Government Failure

II. Second Introduction: Five Reasons Why We Shouldn't Trust the Government

III. Three Clauses That Enable Legislative Action, But Are Used to Excuse Government Overreach
     1. The General Welfare Clause
     2. The Necessary and Proper Clause
     3. The interstate Commerce Clause

IV. Six Laws with Deceptive Names
     4. The Citizens United decision
     5. N.A.F.T.A. (The North American Free Trade Agreement)
     6. The 2008 Emergency Economic Stabilization Act (E.E.S.A)
     7. The Protect Life Act
     8. The Restoring Internet Freedom Act
     9. The Defense of Marriage Act (D.O.M.A.)

V. Eight Self-Defeating Amendments (Plus the Draft)
     10. Amendment I
     11. Amendment II
     12. The military draft
     13. Amendment III
     14. Amendment V
     15. Amendment VIII
     16. Amendment X
     17. Amendment XIII
     18. Amendment XIV



Part 2: The Wars on Terror, Drugs, and Poverty (Including Seventy Bad Laws)


VI. The War on Terror: Fourteen Laws That Fail to Protect People from War, Terrorism, and Violent Crime
     19. Incarceration in jails and prisons
     20. The death penalty
     21. Life sentences

     22. Gun-free zones
     23. Laws requiring publication of gun owners' home addresses
     24. Gun personalization requirements

     25. Gun buyback programs
     26. The War Powers Act of 1973
     27. The state's monopoly on violence
     28. The War on Terror
     29. The 2001 A.U.M.F.
     30. The U.S.A. P.A.T.R.I.O.T. Act
     31. Laws allowing warrantless searches and wiretaps
     32. The Whistleblowers Protection Act



VII. The Wars on Drugs and Our Health: Twenty Laws That Failed to Achieve Affordable Health Care, Failed to Ensure the Legal Sale of Safe Drugs, or Failed to Protect the Environment
     33. The taxation of health goods and services
     34. Federal negotiation of drug prices
     35. Subsidization of pharmaceutical companies
     36. The ban on denying emergency room treatment
     37. The Patient Protection and Affordable Care Act

     38. Ecstasy prohibition
     39. Heroin prohibition

     40. Marijuana prohibition
     41. Marijuana legalization
     42. Alcohol prohibition
     43. Corn subsidies
     44. The criminalization of purchasing alcohol for minors
     45. The criminalization of purchasing tobacco for minors
     46. Laws authorizing the Food and Drug Administration (F.D.A.) to approve or deny pharmaceutical drugs
     47. Laws authorizing the Environmental Protection Agency (E.P.A.)
     48. Federal vehicle emissions standards
     48. The Clean Air Act
     50. The Clean Water Act
     51. Bans on tree-line thinning
     52. The "Roadless Rule"
     53. Superfund sites

VIII. The War on Poverty, Part 1: Eleven Laws That Fail to Protect Workers' Rights and the Interests of Labor Unions
     54. The law that established Labor Day
     55. The Department of Labor and Commerce
     56. The McCarran-Ferguson Act
     57. The Wagner Act (National Labor Relations Act of 1935)
     58. The Taft-Hartley Act of 1947
     59. State Right-to-Work laws
     60. Overtime pay laws
     61. The Federal Reserve's "dual mandate" on interest rates and unemployment
     62. Laws that established the U1, U2, U3, U4, and U5 unemployment measurements
     63. The Employee Free Choice Act, and the Card Check bill

     64. Disability and Medicaid provisions which limit people's ability to be employed and receive benefits at the same time

IX. The War on Poverty, Part 2: Seven Laws That Intended to Protect Minorities and/or Property, But Failed
     65. The federal minimum wage law
     66. The Civil Rights Act of 1964
     67. Redistricting laws
     68. Laws against sagging pants
     69. The Clinton omnibus crime bill
     70. Laws establishing racial quotas for police
     71. The Homestead Act


X. The War on Poverty, Part 3: Six Budgetary and Monetary Policies That Have Led to Economic Ruin
     72. The Agricultural Adjustment Act
     73. Laws establishing natural resource extraction permits
     74. Property tax laws
     75. Sales tax laws
     76. Income tax laws
     77. Laws providing for Unconditional Basic Income programs


XI. The War on Poverty, Part 4: Ten Laws That Intended to Make the Markets Free, But Rigged Them Instead
     78. The Enumerated Power which authorizes Congress to coin and regulate money
     79. Laws limiting usury
     80. The Sherman Antitrust Act
     81. Laws enabling the U.S. Patent and Trademark Office
     82. Executive Order 6102 (which enabled gold confiscations)
     83. The Emergency Banking Act of 1933
     84. Laws authorizing the Federal Deposit Insurance Corporation (F.D.I.C.)
     85. Laws enabling the Securities and Exchange Commission (S.E.C.)
     86. The Glass-Steagall Act
     87. Laws authorizing the Consumer Financial Protection Bureau (C.F.P.B.)


Part 3: Other Topics (Including Twenty-Five Bad Laws, and a Conclusion)


XII. Five Failed Laws and Policies Related to Insurance
     88. Insurance regulations
     89. Home insurance regulations, and the Department of Housing and Urban Development (H.U.D.)

     90. Laws establishing public firefighting forces
     91. Insurance regulations regarding emergency medical care
     92. Insurance regulations regarding public school students' medications

XIII. Four Laws That Tried to Prevent Frivolous Lawsuits, But Go Too Far

     93. Legal immunity for gun manufacturers
     94. Legal immunity for the military and police
     95. Laws enabling the granting of L.L.C. designation
     96. Statutes of limitations on reporting rape, sexual assault, sexual abuse, and sexual harassment
XIV. Five Laws That Tried to Protect the Rights or Safety of Women and Homosexuals, But Failed
     97. Laws requiring fees and licenses to get married

     98. The Roe v. Wade U.S. Supreme Court decision
     99. Legal limitations and prohibitions on abortion
     100. The Violence Against Women Act (V.A.W.A.) of 1994
     101. Legislative proposals to require women to register for the draft

XV. Eight Laws and Programs That Fail to Protect Children
     102. Laws establishing minimum ages for consent to sex

     103. Laws establishing minimum ages for consent to marriage
     104. The federal law establishing a minimum age for consent to sex
     105. Laws requiring registration as a sex offender
     106. Laws establishing Child Protective Services -type agencies
     107. The federal law which established the National Center for Missing and Exploited Children
     108. Policies against establishing laws requiring minimum ages for tattooing and piercing
     109. Social Security Title IV-D (child support)


XVI. Three More Terrible Laws
     110. The Enumerated Power which authorizes Congress to "fix the standard of weights and measurements"
     111. Laws which regulate identity theft, in regards to banks' and credit agencies' customer information
     112. Laws which regulate identity theft, in regards to immigrants' Social Security

XVII. Conclusion: New Laws Don't Work
 






Content


Part 1: Introduction (Including Seventeen Bad Basic Laws of Government)


I. First Introduction: Government Failure

     Can you name a law that has ever worked? A law that has worked the way it was intended?
     In our society, we're used to talking about market failures; high prices, high profits, price manipulation, monopolies, etc.. But I submit that we're not talking enough about government failures. Things like regulatory capture, and the erection of corporate privilege. Those things are every bit as important to talk about as market failures, because they cause most of those market failures in the first place (giving businesses power by handing them taxpayer money and/or writing special privileges for them into the law).
     In this essay, I will name ninety-five laws (or types of laws) in the United States – most of them federal laws – and explain how they achieve the exact opposite of their desired or intended effect. In explaining this, I will defend the idea that most attempts by the voting American public, to secure some equal liberty or new positive right – in many different policy arenas – have historically resulted in surrendering more decision-making power to the government regarding those policy issues, instead of resulting in more freedom or equality for the people.
     I will focus on two basic sets of policy areas:
     1) general constitutional powers which enable or limit government; and
     2) the failures of the “War on Terror”, the “War on Drugs”, and the “War on Poverty”.
In discussing the failures of those “wars”, I will explain how putting too much trust in the government to solve problems, has led to disastrous declines in the quality of policy regarding the military, policing, health care, legal and illegal drugs, and various economic issues pertaining to relations between workers and employers (and the government).
     And all of these issues are interrelated, I might add. Our police and military enforce not only the “War on Terror”, but they also defend (or decline to defend) ourselves and our property, enforce the “War on Drugs” and the “War on Poverty”, they enforce the financial and business and labor regulations.
     Whether it is constitutional that those agents enforce those laws – that is, whether the enforcement of these laws, is itself “legal” in the first place – should be considered an issue of extreme importance. So should the issues of whether the police, or other government officials, publicly-protected companies, should do what they're told; as well as the matter of whether the policy works in the first place; and, at that, works they way it was intended to work.
     [Note: The fact that I have included a specific law, or types of law, below, should not necessarily be construed to mean that I believe that such laws, or types of laws, could never work, nor that I believe they do never work. In many cases, I do doubt whether such laws could ever work; but in some of the cases listed below, I am merely criticizing the manner in which those laws have been historically implemented, and saying that the laws did not work as they were intended to work.]


II. Second Introduction: Five Reasons Why We Shouldn't Trust the Government

     There is a popular libertarian saying whose author is unknown. It was popularized by Barry Goldwater, often mistakenly attributed to Thomas Jefferson, and began circulating in 1950s American newspapers. It goes like this: “A government that is big enough to give you everything you want, is big enough to take it all away.” Whomever said it, it certainly seems true.
     We should not trust the government to solve our problems, for five main reasons; because of:
     1) the government's power to regulate ­ or not regulate – corporations (and to break up, or not break up, monopolies);
     2) the government's power to create monopolies and to create corporations;
     3) the corruptibility of the licensing and permit systems;
     4) the moral hazard involved in trusting the government and only government to solve our problems; and
     5) regulatory capture (the process whereby an industry comes to be “regulated” by the same people who work in that industry).

     If we trust the government to regulate corrupt companies, and tax owners who profit off of the public dime, then the government will do exactly that. I'm not doubting the government's ability, nor its will, to do those things. But shouldn't corrupt C.E.O.s, and people who embezzle taxpayer money, go to jail, instead of just having their taxes raised, and new “restraints” placed on them?
     But the issue isn't just that we're not jailing criminals if they happen to be wealthy; it's also that the government usually incentivizes wealthy criminals to commit their crimes. It does this through giving them special legal and financial protections, and devoting more money and police resources towards protecting the rich and their investments than the poor and their homes.
     Why should we trust the government to break up or regulate companies, or tax them adequately, or decline to abuse their privileges? For two simple reasons: 1) Government cannot be trusted to regulate nor break-up monopolies, because government (that is, state government) is a monopoly. 2) Why would government want to limit the power of corporations, when it's the government that's creating all of these corporations in the first place?
     Another endemic problem with our government is political; the manner in which large companies manage to secure taxpayer money and privileges for themselves, having asked for those things as a consolation for being taxed and regulated. Those companies and their lobbyists make it impossible to pass meaningful economic reforms that help the poor, because wealthy companies get away with insisting to legislators that all laws designed to help the poor, help them less than they help the rich.
     For all of these reasons, and the following, trusting government is a terrible idea, and here are ninety-two reasons why.


III. Three Clauses That Enable Legislative Action, But Are Used to Excuse Government Overreach

     The first three laws I will discuss, enable government but intend to severely limit it. They do the opposite of what they intend to do, because their language is abused by legislators, so as to excuse more government overreach and more distortion of the meaning of the law, instead of abiding by the limitation originally intended.

     These three laws are the General Welfare Clause, the Necessary and Proper Clause, and the Interstate Commerce Clause.

     1. The General Welfare Clause.
     The General Welfare Clause is a part of the Taxing and Spending Clause (found in Article I, Section 8, Clause 1 of the U.S. Constitution). It is the first clause of the “Enumerated Powers”; the eighteen specifically authorized powers of Congress.

     The General Welfare Clause empowers Congress to “lay and collect Taxes, Duties, Imposts, and Excises, to pay the Debts and provide for the common Defence and general Welfare of the United States; but all Duties, Imposts and Excises shall be uniform throughout the United States;”.
The General Welfare Clause does the opposite of what it intends to do, because the meanings of “general” and “welfare” in “General Welfare” Clause are being distorted.

     “General” means that duties, imposts, and excise taxes shall be uniform throughout the country. Basically, it means that the burden of taxation must be equal (at least in regards to those types of taxes). However, even if the burden of income taxation fell on states equally (which it doesn't), there is no proof that income taxation is good policy even when it can be done constitutionally.
     Additionally, “welfare” meant “well-being” when the Constitution was written, so it is arguable as to whether something like a “Department of Health, Education, and Welfare”, or modern welfare programs, are permissible under this clause of the Constitution.
     Thus, distortion of the terms “general” and “welfare” has permitted an uneven income tax burden across the states, in order to spend that money on - not the general welfare (which really just means the equal benefit of all people across the country), but – the vague or specific welfare. Any and every type of spending is allowed, to benefit any and every particular social safety net project or corporate welfare giveaway. And so, with no rationale as to why we're spending this money on these particular people and causes, we justify taxing people with no rationale as to whether we're taxing them equally.
     The General Welfare Clause enables government overreach, although its intent was to limit government. But I say “its intent”; the law doesn't have any intent. I mean to refer to the intent of the legislators who wrote it. And they, of course, worked for the government. We should expect no less, for as Thrasymachus explained, justice always serves “the advantage of the stronger”. This is to say that any government we can elect, will always rule in its own benefit; in favor of incumbents, and in favor of continuing the same style and structure of government.
     The General Welfare Clause would better be called the “Specific Welfare Clause”, the “Vague Welfare Clause”, or the “General Harm Clause”.

     2. The Necessary and Proper Clause
     The final clause in Article I, Section 8 of the Constitution, empowers the Congress “To make all Laws which shall be necessary and proper for carrying into execution the foregoing Powers, and all other Powers vested by this Constitution in the Government of the United States...”.
     The Necessary and Proper Clause is often used to excuse doing whatever people think is necessary and proper for the government to do. But the term, as used in the Constitution, does not mean that at all. What is “necessary and proper” here, is not for the government to do whatever it wants, nor whatever the people wants; the intent here is to limit government's ability to do anything other than what is necessary and proper to execute “the foregoing Powers”.
     And what are “the foregoing Powers”? The Enumerated Powers. The preceding seventeen powers of Congress which are named before that sentence in the Constitution. The powers to create military and diplomatic policy, and monetary and treasury policy, and to punish piracy and regulate slavery, protect scientific discoveries, designate post roads, and little else.
     Congress was never intended to have the authority to do anything other than the seventeen things listed in Article I, Section 8, and the eighteenth congressional power enables Congress to do what is necessary to do those other seventeen things, and nothing else.
     The Necessary and Proper Clause would better be called the “Unnecessary and Improper Clause”, or the “Do What You Feel Clause”.

     3. The Interstate Commerce Clause
     The third clause in Article I, Section 8, empowers the Congress “To regulate Commerce with foreign Nations, and among the several States, and with the Indian tribes.”
     Today, this clause is used to justify regulating not only business activity which substantially affects interstate commerce, but also anything that could remotely be described as economic activity, which could theoretically be construed as subtly affecting interstate commerce in any small way.
     The power to regulate interstate Commerce Clause is not even used; much less as intended. The clause intended to restrict economic regulation to what is necessary to prevent states from passing preferential laws that unduly favor the domestic commerce occurring within those states, over commerce from other states. Today, states are allowed to propose laws like this – for example, a law proposed in Minnesota that would have imposed a tax on craft beers from out-of-state - without anyone noticing that they violate the interstate Commerce Clause.
     The Commerce Clause thus enables Congress to regulate any and all economic activity, and enables states to consider laws that violate the Constitution and destroy the fairness of the American free trade zone, when the clause originally intended to strictly limit the power of the federal government to regulate interstate commerce, and to limit the power of the state governments to pass laws that protect local state business interests over the interests of other states.
     The interstate Commerce Clause would more appropriately be called the “Let the States Unfairly Protect Their Own Companies Clause” or the "Let the Federal Government Regulate Whatever it Wants Clause".



IV. Six Laws with Deceptive Names

     There are many laws in America – the P.A.T.R.I.O.T. Act and the Patient Protection Affordable Care Act, for example (which I'll get to later) – which have deceptive names. These deceptive names reveal precisely how the law does the opposite of what it states it is trying to do.


     4. Citizens United
     The Citizens United v. Federal Election Commission Supreme Court decision allows unlimited campaign donations; on the basis of the idea that donations to political campaigns are a form of free expression which is protected by the First Amendment to the Constitution. The ruling has divided the country.
     “Citizens United” would better be called “Citizens Divided”.

     5. N.A.F.T.A. (The North American Free Trade Agreement)
     The 1993/1994 North American Free Trade Agreement was a multilateral trade compact (or treaty) between several national governments. Its intention was to promote free trade, but it only worked towards a zero-tariff scenario and real free trade.
     Furthermore, N.A.F.T.A. went backwards on protecting property, the environment, and the sovereignty of foreign countries. It did this by allowing the Mexican Constitution to be amended so as to allow the exploitation of native land in Mexico by international property developers (among other negative consequences of the deal).
     Moreover, trade deals can be negotiated without governments, and they are probably even best negotiated without governments. Thus, N.A.F.T.A. achieved the opposite of free trade; it was a government-managed trade deal.
     Some criticize N.A.F.T.A. for creating a “North American free trade zone” that threatens to flood America with cheap products, cheap labor, or both. But that is to criticize the deal for making trade “too free”. I criticize it because it makes trade too unfree.
     The North American Free Trade Agreement would more appropriately be called “the North American Unfree Trade Agreement” or the “Make North America Submit Economically to the United States Agreement”.

     6. The Emergency Economic Stabilization Act
     The 2008 Emergency Economic Stabilization Act (E.E.S.A) was a congressional bailout measure intended to mitigate the damage of the 2007-08 financial crisis. While its stated intention was to “stabilize the economy”, what it actually did was authorize the Secretary of the Treasury to buy up to $700 billion in troubled assets.
     The E.E.S.A. was just the first in a series of bailouts, which affected nine major companies. Financial analysts have argued as to whether the total cost of the bailouts and restructuring ended up amounting to $10, $12, or even $29.6 trillion dollars, as opposed to the initial $700 billion troubled asset purchase authorization which made the Troubled Asset Relief Program “necessary” to create.
     Thus, the Emergency Economic Stabilization Act would better be called the “Emergency Economic Destabilization Act”, because it was a risky piece of legislation that put the economy in further peril.

     7. The Protect Life Act
The Protect Life Act, which was passed by Congress in 2011 but not signed into law, would have prohibited Obamacare funding from being spent on abortion. Its express purpose would have been to protect the life of the unborn fetus.
     However, that proposed law also would have made it legal for hospitals to deny abortions to pregnant women even if they have life-threatening conditions.
     Thus, the Protect Life Act would more appropriately be called the “Protect Fetus' Lives Only Act” or the “Let Women Die in Childbirth Act”.

     8. The Restoring Internet Freedom Act
     The Restoring Internet Freedom Act, enacted in 2018, destroys the freedom of the internet - its open-source, collaborative commons, peer-to-peer nature - because it prohibits the F.C.C. (Federal Communication Corporation) from classifying I.S.P.s (internet service providers) as common carriers. The law also prohibits the F.C.C. from “imposing certain regulations on providers of such service”.
     Thus, the Restoring Internet Freedom Act, would more appropriately be called “the Destroying Internet Freedom Act”.

     9. The Defense of Marriage Act (D.O.M.A.)
     The Defense of Marriage Act, which was federal law from 1996 to 2015, prohibited married same-sex couples from collecting federal benefits.
     Thus, the Defense of Marriage Act defended solely the marriages of heterosexuals, in treating same-sex couples in a discriminatory manner. So it doesn't defend marriages; if it did, then it would defend all marriages (between consenting adults), and it would want there to be more marriages. But the people who wrote and approved D.O.M.A. didn't want that.
     That's why the Defense of Marriage Act would better be termed the “Defend Straight Marriages Only Act”, the “Destruction of Marriage Act”, the “Preferential Treatment for Straight Couples Act”, or the “Offend Gay Marriages Act”.



[Explanations for examples of government failure #10-#110 will appear on this page at a later date.]






Written on July 27th, 2019
Based on Notes Taken in June and July 2019

Written for the Bughouse Square Debates, held in Chicago, Illinois on July 27th, 2019
and delivered in part at the debates

Edited on August 13th, 2019


Tuesday, August 7, 2018

Capitalism is Incompatible with Free Markets, Voluntary Exchange, and Libertarianism


Table of Contents

1. The 2018 Libertarian National Convention
2. The Debate Over the Libertarian Party Platform
3. The Debate Over Economic Systems and Property
4. Wealth Acquisition: Chrematistics vs. Economics
5. Libertarian Capitalism vs. Libertarian Socialism
6. The Social Safety Net, Basic Income, and Revolution
7. Restoring the Libertarian Alliance with the Left


Content

1. The 2018 Libertarian National Convention

     Since the summer of 2017, the Libertarian Party has been abuzz about the rise of the party's Libertarian Socialist (abbbreviated LibSoc) Caucus, one of at least forty caucuses in the party. The existence of a Libertarian Socialist Caucus in the traditionally free-market party has caused some controversy, especially considering that the party also has an Anti-Socialist Caucus as well.
     At the 2018 Libertarian National Convention in New Orleans, Louisiana – held from June 30th to July 3rd, 2018 - Nicholas Sarwark retained his national chair position after debating three challengers. Those challengers included Joshua Smith, Christopher Thrasher, and Matt Kuehnel, a LibSoc Caucus member who's also running for state house of representatives from Michigan's 22nd District.
     Sparks flew at the debate when chair candidate Joshua Smith called Kuehnel a “confirmed communist”, and implied that Kuehnel's being a socialist or communist meant the party was being infiltrated by authoritarians. Kuehnel asserted the same about Smith, citing his concern that Smith seems to be cozying up to the Alt-Right. While Kuehnel insisted that he is an anarchist and a libertarian communist, not an authoritarian communist, Smith pledged to help grow the party by “reaffirming our principles, including property rights, to make sure this country knows what we stand for.”
     The exchange between Joshua Smith and Matt Kuehnel exemplify one of the most important debates going on right now in the Libertarian Party; whether the party will support free markets or capitalism. You might be thinking, “Aren't those the same thing?” Well, that's certainly what followers of Ludwig von Mises, and the anarcho-capitalists, want us to believe. But is that true? Could it be possible that capitalism is a free-market system, but only when it's not “crony capitalism”, as these people claim?


2. The Debate Over the Libertarian Party Platform

     The Libertarian Party (L.P.) of the United States was founded in 1971. The following year, the party held a convention in Denver, Colorado, nominated John Hospers for the presidency and Tonie Nathan for the vice-presidency, and laid out its national platform for the first time.
     In 1972, the Statement of Principles of the L.P.'s platform originally read, “People... should be left free by government to deal with one another as free traders on a free market; and the resultant economic system, the only one compatible with the protection of man's rights, is laissez-faire capitalism.”
     However, at the L.P.'s 1974 national convention in Dallas, Texas, the Statement of Principles was modified, so as to read, “People... should be left free by government to deal with one another as free traders; and the resultant economic system, the only one compatible with the protection of individual rights, is the free market.”
     Thus, “man's rights” was changed to “individual rights” (to reflect the need to make that language more inclusive and gender-neutral), and “laissez-faire capitalism” was changed to “the free market”. This change was part of what came to be known as the Dallas Accord, an attempt to unite factions within the L.P..

     This conflict between socialist-leaning libertarians and capitalist-leaning libertarians is by no means a new thing; it has been going on since the party's infancy. Not only does this economic divide exist within the party, it also affects the conversations the party is having about whether the party should favor a minimal state (by whatever definition) or else the abolition of the state altogether.
     Libertarian socialists and anarcho-capitalists have somewhat different ideas about what a state looks like, and different ideas about which economic systems are most strongly associated with statism and control. They also have very different ideas about whether the presence of a statist government helps protect and foster an environment of economic growth, or whether it instead fundamentally interferes with voluntary exchange, the free flow of labor and capital, and the spontaneous adjustment of prices according to the laws of supply and demand.
     The so-called “right-libertarians” insist that terms like “capitalism”, “property rights”, and “self-ownership” should be included in the L.P. platform; while “left-libertarians” are more likely to question the rhetoric of self-ownership, question what makes property ownership legitimate, and question whether explicitly endorsing “capitalism” could lead to the oppression of people who wish to practice socialism voluntarily.

     At the 2006 Libertarian National Convention in Portland, Oregon, delegates deleted a whopping 46 planks from the party's then 61-plank platform. This change came to be known as “the Portland massacre”. Delegates also added the sentence “Government exists to protect the rights of every individual including life, liberty and property.”
     While right-libertarians may rejoice at the addition of this sentence – being that it arguably reflects a desire to explicitly endorse property rights – it is troublesome for all libertarians, because it arguably justifies the existence of the government, based on the idea that if government was created with the intention of protecting life, liberty, and property, then it should continue to do so. But on the other hand, it might simply mean that if government must exist, then it should only do basic things, like protect life, liberty, and property.
     Radicals and anarchists in the party weren't pleased by what came soon after this change; an influx of constitutionalists and libertarian-conservatives into the party, which appeared to be the result of the L.P.'s new embrace of property rights and government protection of individual rights.
     People like Bob Barr (the 2008 presidential nominee) and judge Jim Gray (the 2012 vice-presidential nominee) rubbed these radical and anarchist libertarians the wrong way. One such radical was 2008 presidential candidate Christine Smith, who said in advance of Bob Barr's impending nomination, “Put a real libertarian on the ballot”, while also criticizing Barr's history with the C.I.A. and his “yes” vote on the U.S.A. P.A.T.R.I.O.T. Act.
     The Portland massacre arguably set the stage for the recent influx of Alt-Righters - and Trump supporters who think they're libertarians - into the L.P., likely spurred-on by the party's refusal to distance itself from Ron Paul (the L.P.'s 1988 presidential nominee before and after being a Republican, who continues to hire and associate with racial supremacists).

     Another issue dividing people in the L.P. along left-vs.-right lines, is whether the party was wise to nominate Gary Johnson for president for the second time in 2016, after he said that he would have signed the Civil Rights Act of 1964, even though it prohibited discrimination in “public accommodations” (restaurants, theaters, hotels, etc., which serve members of the public). Right-libertarians view these properties as private, and believe that they should be run according to the rules set by the owner, rather than by government.
     However, it's not just the farthest-right members of the party who oppose Johnson on this issue; in fact, Gary Johnson was the only one of the L.P.'s five presidential candidates who refused to condemn the 1964 C.R.A. as a violation of the rights of property owners. While Johnson refused to explain the reasoning for his position during the party's five-way presidential debate, during that campaign he told a crowd in Utah that as president, he would not be prepared to regress on that issue, or go back in progress, on what he considered to be an important civil right.
     I personally believe that Johnson's position on the 1964 C.R.A. should not disqualify him from nomination, that the Dallas Accord helped the party, and that the changes made in Portland in 2006 had some negative consequences. I would like to see the party pursue “Bottom Unity” - cooperation between all libertarian philosophies, right or left – and bring more radicals, anarchists, and even libertarian socialists, into the fold.
     While more radicals could arguably lead to people leaving the party, the only people likely to be upset by this, are the exact people whose “authoritarian entryism” we are concerned about. These flag-waving bootlickers, who believe that evil is necessary, will not be missed by anyone. At least not anyone who is serious about making sure that the party supports freedom against force, instead of just a merciful-enough form of tyranny that tries to achieve freedom through enforcement.
     People who make excuse after excuse for the state, and for harsh and exclusionary immigration and borders measures which discriminate on the basis of national origin, have no business making public policy, let alone business in a party which supports non-discrimination in the public sphere (as well as individual civil liberties, including the right to a fair legal process, and equal justice under the law). These are the kinds of people whom we should hope are encouraged to leave the party - whether due to an influx of anarchists and socialists or not - so that they stop tainting the Libertarian Party with a bad reputation through associating with it.

3. The Debate Over Economic Systems and Property

     Although the Libertarian Party platform now supports property rights, and seems ambivalent about whether government is necessary, it nevertheless excludes the term capitalism. Instead, it supports free markets and voluntary exchange. The term “laissez faire” - literally French for “let them do”, referring to producers, but more accurately, “leave them be” or “leave them alone” - is no longer part of the platform, but its meaning (or at least its connotation) is retained through the inclusion of the phrase “free market”.
     Therefore, it could easily be argued that the Libertarian Party did stop supporting “capitalism”, at least in name, just three years after the party was founded. Thus, it wouldn't be a big leap to infer - from the facts that the party supports free markets and voluntary exchange, and that it explicitly excluded the word “capitalism” - that the party is against capitalism.
     After all, there are non-capitalist economic systems which support “property rights” - again, at least in name – but which do not support capitalism. These include Mutualism, Georgism, anarchism, and libertarian socialism. All of these (except, arguably, the latter) might be perfectly willing to support a libertarian society or a system of voluntary exchange, if not for right-wing libertarians' insistence that that is exactly the “free-market capitalism” towards which they wish to strive.

     In my opinion, capitalism is compatible with neither free markets nor a libertarian society. If free markets are what Rothbardian “anarcho-capitalists” (“AnCaps”) and Misesian “free-market capitalists” want us to believe they are, then market “freedom” allows people to own things they didn't earn. Capitalists believe that it's acceptable to accrue unearned income through speculation; through collusion and strategic combination to establish oligopolies; and through profit, rent, interest, and usury; claiming the “right of increase” to justify it. These practices have little, if anything, to do with entrepreneurship and meritocracy.
     Essentially, capitalists believe that it's not a violation of the Non-Aggression Principle (N.A.P.) to collude with other property owners to make money by excluding people from what they need, and that exploiting people's labor doesn't violate the N.A.P.. This is because capitalists believe that working for employers is always voluntary, because the value of our labor is subjective, so therefore the laborer's rights are not violated because they are not directly aggressed, nor threatened, into working for an employer. Additionally, because capitalists believe (or, more accurately, assume) that working for oneself, earning one's needs through foraging and hunting and gathering, and otherwise getting by while avoiding working for other people, are viable options; viable alternatives to selling one's labor. When it comes to rent, capitalists believe that a person has the choice of living anywhere else, so therefore the housing unit to which they pay rent is a matter of their personal choice.
     Libertarian socialists, of course, reject that pro-capitalism argument, and believe that it is an N.A.P. violation to use any sort of pressure to get people to give up any part of the product of their labor (or their full rights thereto). Socialists believe that capitalists use coercion and exploitation as tools to put people into states of duress, such that they are indirectly threatened into settling for working for some particular employer and living in some particular housing unit.
     To repeat, workers and renters are not directly threatened; rather, they are indirectly and implicitly coerced. While nature itself offers the possibility of abundance, it also imposes the inevitable risk of starvation if what's produced is not efficiently and equitably received. Whether or not they directly benefit from the tyranny and largess of the state, and from its historical enclosures of the commons, private owners and capitalists coerce laborers and renters into accepting bad terms of employment and shoddy living arrangements.
     Landlords and employers do this by extending the threat which is potentially posed by nature, to people near them - using the Pauline, colonial, and Leninist maxim "He who does not work shall not eat" - in order to issue an implicit threat to laborers and workers. This threat coerces them, under duress, to "choose" to accept the least oppressive or most convenient employment opportunity, and to assent to, and settle for, the least shabby apartment, or living arrangement of least resistance. Which is occasionally living where one works, which - due to the fact that the laborer is essentially earning money to buy his way off of living on someone else's private property - can bear many similarities to indentured servitude.
     Capitalism relies on convincing people that things are worth less than the cost of producing them, and that people are worth whatever the cost of supporting their survival is. Additionally, that people should endorse the faulty premise of self-ownership, which arguably uses rhetoric that reduces human beings to mere pieces of "owned" property. In my opinion, this line of thinking seems a little too closely associated with the notion that it is permissible to contractually sell oneself into slavery. Any true "anarcho"-capitalist ought to know that without the state, nobody would be able to enforce such a contract. If a private, voluntary contract enforcement agency tried to enforce such an "agreement", free people who understand that this is wrong would use their boycott power, and if need be, even come to the aid of those who are unable to defend themselves or refuse to. We cannot assume that contractual slaves truly consent, simply because they refuse to defend themselves from their "willing" captors; this is not true consent, but assent; submission, the giving up of struggle.
     Capitalists extract surplus rent and profit which they didn't earn rightfully, because they didn't earn it through their own labor, but instead, somebody else's. Libertarian socialists see this - rightfully, in my opinion - as a form of stealing, and thus, an obvious violation of the Non-Aggression Principle. This is why capitalism is incompatible with voluntary exchange; because capitalism relies on involuntary exchange. It relies on veiled threats - the implicit threat of starvation on the street - against those who refuse to sell their labor, and against homeless vagrants who trespass upon private property (which they do because they cannot help but do so, having no private property of their own).
     Although I once believed “anarcho-capitalism” to be the fullest expression of anarchism, I now understand that “individualist anarchism” and “market anarchism” are distinct schools of thought. That is why I no longer support the belief that these are inevitable features of capitalism, whether in a stateless society or under the supervision of government or the state.


4. Wealth Acquisition: Chrematistics vs. Economics

     Capitalism is usually defined as an economic system in which the means of production are owned in private hands. The operation of those privately-owned means of production for profit, and the establishment of a strong system of property rights, are often included in that definition.
     Left-leaning libertarians, on the other hand – like those who describe themselves as “Bleeding Heart Libertarians” (the name of a left-libertarian blog) – say Markets Not Capitalism (the name of a collection of libertarian and anarchist essays, edited by Bleeding Heart Libertarians contributors Gary E. Chartier and Charles W. Johnson).
     To these so-called “left-wing market-anarchists” (or “free-market anti-capitalists”, or “market-oriented social-anarchists”), supporting markets while opposing capitalism is about supporting the voluntary exchange of goods and services, but without endorsing a necessarily for-profit system, or any system in which private owners have little to no responsibilities to their communities.
     Capitalism allows people to acquire through “chrematistics”, which Aristotle considered form of wealth acquisition which is less likely to be “natural” than economics. Chrematistics, in Aristotle's conception, can be either “natural” or “artificial”, but compared to economics, it is more likely to result in acquisition purely for the sake of acquisition (which can lead to hoarding, conspicuous consumption, waste, destruction, and to production that aids in achieving these ends).
     Economics, on the other hand – coming from the root oikos, meaning “household” - literally refers to the art, study, and science of household wealth management. Economics thus has a closer association with the earning of income through labor, which, according to Aristotle, is an arguably more “natural” form of wealth acquisition. Economist Henry George coined the term "unearned income" (the opposite of earned income) to describe these more "unnatural" forms of acquisition.

     It could be argued that, as forms of wealth acquisition, socialism focuses on economics, while capitalism focuses on chrematistics. Socialism - in which people fully own the things they need, and can trade them away at will 
because they fully own them, and thus don't need to ask nor pay anyone for permission to do so - focuses on the earning of face value through labor, for the benefit of the household. On the other hand, capitalism - with its rent, interest, profit, and usury - creates value through the manipulation of value of itself, rather than through earning. This is done through subtly coercing people into depending on employers and landlords for their needs, and into giving up their right to own in exchange for the "convenience" of renting, which deprives them of the full right to use and trade their possessions as they please (because they're mere possessions registered to and owned by someone else, rather than their actual property).
     Although capitalism is a chrematistic form of wealth acquisition, market-based systems of free voluntary exchange do not have to be. As long as they are not rigged, and as long as we actively free the markets (i.e., create "freed markets", instead of just calling the rigged markets we have now "free" for convenience's sake), then voluntary exchange can thrive. That's because only when the markets are not rigged to support capitalism over free markets and socialism, can people have the freedom to exchange things that fully belong to them, and to nobody else who's trying to extort them for the privilege of using or occupying those things.


5. Libertarian Capitalism vs. Libertarian Socialism

     Capitalism makes no demand that the earner play any role in the defense, nor the upkeep, of his property claim, nor that he frequently use it. Nor does capitalism insist that an owner actually acquire a parcel of landed property through his own labor - without stealing or killing or kicking people off their land - and without buying it from gangs of organized criminals who stole and killed in order to get it. Anyone who knows about the enclosure of the commons, the Lockean proviso, the principle “price the limit of cost”, and the ideas of absentee property ownership and usufructory (use-based) property rights, will tell you that.
     The Non-Aggression Principle cannot permit the acquisition, nor the keeping, of property which was stolen, and which rightfully belongs to someone else. Nor can it logically permit the transfer of stolen property, especially not for profit. While left-libertarians routinely cite the enclosure of the English commons, and episodes of mass displacement of people in other societies, as the obvious reason as to why “rent is theft”, capitalists often deliberately ignore the idea that conquest – and buying conquered land from tyrannical, genocidal governments – is neither a fair nor a free way to acquire wealth and property.

     Not only are free market economics and voluntary exchange inconsistent with capitalism; they are also inconsistent with unlimited property rights. Capitalists often make fantastical, unenforceable claims to property, such that they are practically unlimited as to what a private owner can do with the resources on his property (whether it's their possessions, the groundwater and soil and minerals beneath the surface, or even living things dwelling on it).
     The capitalist view has historically been one which has lacked any semblance of a feeling of responsibility to assistance in the maintenance of the ecological quality of its surroundings, on the surface of the planet which sustains all of our lives. It treats living things – plant, animal, and human alike – as if they were dead pieces of property, to be commodified and capitalized-on.
     But not only are unlimited property rights inconsistent with free exchange; unlimited property rights are inconsistent with themselves. The construction of the planned wall along the U.S.-Mexico border is interfering with the already existing private property rights of homeowners living near the border.      This wall, whether completed or not, will obstruct the free flow of travelers, workers, and capital; not only of people who are trying to come into the United States without permission, but also of United States citizens – white and Hispanic alike – who live near the border, but who may soon become enclosed; walled-off from their places of employment and from half of their community.

     Contrary to capitalists' claims that socialism, like statism, enables people to be lazy and irresponsible, and live off of the production of other people, capitalism is just as likely to enable this lifestyle; just for the lucky few, instead of for large numbers of people. Including people who could stand to benefit by working fewer hours, but engaging in more efficient production.
     Capitalism allows lazy people to make money that they didn't earn through their own effort, but by colluding with other property owners to exclude people from their property. It also allows irresponsible entrepreneurs to make malinvestments, and to externalize the costs of those improper investments onto unaware actors.
     Under statism, people are allowed to do this at taxpayer expense; because the people's taxes subsidize their businesses, and pay for their police protection, and for their L.L.C. status (which confers a privilege to be immune from legal responsibility). Additionally, landlords pay their mortgages off with our money, while they maintain their investments without assuming any personal financial risk, and bosses balance their checkbooks through profits which were supposed to be the wages of workers.
     A right-libertarian might argue that what I have just described is merely what capitalism does  under the current system (statism, which we can't avoid). However, there are a few "anarcho-capitalist", right-libertarian, and paleo-libertarian writers who have argued that corporations, liability limitations, and patrolling officers would still exist in the absence of a state (people like Murray Rothbard and Walter Block). This ought to cast some doubt on the capitalists' dedication to statelessness. Any "anarcho-capitalist" who disagrees with those ideas should make those disagreements known, if he wishes to be taken seriously.

6. The Social Safety Net, Basic Income, and Revolution

     A social safety net is just a Band-Aid on capitalism. A social safety net is not socialism, no matter how large, robust, costly, or inclusive it is. More taxes, and more free money from the government, will not lead to socialism; it will only lead to a bigger welfare state. It will also lead to more capitalism, because more and more people will fall victim to the foolish ideas that capitalism (rather than land and labor) is the source of all production, and that the capitalist economy is the only way to produce enough to sustain the government and the large welfare state.
     That is why a universal basic income guarantee (U.B.I., or B.I.G.) will not be successful. First, because U.B.I. programs are destined to fail, due to the inflating effects which are bound to be the result of such a policy. Second, basic income "experiments" are destined to fail, for the simple reason that a universal B.I.G. is supposed to be universal. That is, funds are supposed to be distributed to everyone in society, no matter how rich or how poor they are. So of course the basic income experiment in Canada failed; it only benefited several thousand people, and everyone who was excluded from those benefits had to suffer the negative consequences of not receiving any funds. 
     Third, a U.B.I. will not be successful; not unless and until all businesses – large and small alike – lose every single one of their subsidies, bailouts, patents and trademarks, L.L.C. statuses, trade promotions (through import tariffs), utilities discounts, easy-credit loans, deposit insurance, and police protection. Otherwise, once we have the U.B.I., the only things we'll be able to buy, will be made by companies that are protected from failure, and which keep themselves afloat using our taxpayer money, whether we choose to buy from them in person or not.
     Still, despite what Lysander Spooner has suggested on the matter, the right-libertarians insist that we are free, simply because we get to choose from which of these masters (read: bosses and landlords) we are to toil. Remember, we don't just work for our bosses, we work for our landlords too.

     I suspect that a transition from capitalism to socialism would likely not happen without a revolution; not even if that capitalism system already features a social safety net and an extensive bureaucracy, like the American system does now (which, by the way, could also be adequately described as mercantilistic, or as approaching a state of autarky).
     I believe that an orderly, legitimate transition – that is to say, a legal transition - from capitalism to socialism, would only be likely and conceivable in a fully functioning liberal democracy. Therefore, a nation like the United States, – with such strong traditions of republicanism, capitalism, private property rights, and anti-communism – would almost certainly not become socialist without a majority of support among the political ruling class, the wealthiest handful of citizens, and the military and police.
     “State socialism” - a term associated with Prussian leader Otto von Bismarck - aimed to find a compromise between socialism and capitalism, essentially settling on a capitalist state with a social safety net. Fascism, national socialism (Nazism), and other “Third Way” systems, aimed to find a similar compromise (which, of course, resulted in a wave of ultra-nationalism, and the rise of the Axis Powers, leading up to World War II). Nevertheless, “libertarian” capitalists should realize that socialism is compatible with free markets, in addition to capitalism.


6. Restoring the Libertarian Alliance with the Left

     In my opinion, the Libertarian Party should address issues like property and economic systems in its platform. It should do this by making conscious efforts to remove or edit passages which appear to suggest that government is necessary, that the party needs to support capitalism over socialism, or that the party's economic system is anything other than one which focuses on voluntary exchange of property which was justly acquired (rather than stolen and extorted, even if that theft was done "legitimately" according to the letter of the law).
     I hope that the delegates to the next Libertarian National Convention amend the platform so as to even more resolutely declare that the state is unnecessary, that it legalizes its own crime, and that statism is fundamentally built on the same premise as terrorism (that is, the use of violence in order to achieve political goals).
     I hope that this will assist in bringing more radicals and anarchists into the fold of the libertarian movement, more "small-l" libertarians into the L.P., and help restore our alliance with the Bookchinite "libertarian communalists" and other anti-war Leftists, with whom Libertarians were more closely aligned prior to 1980, when, as Agorist Samuel E. Konkin III described it, the "Kochtopus" and the "Partyarchs" took the L.P. over, and nominated wealthy industrialist David Koch for the vice presidency after he donated half a million dollars to the L.P..
     Making the Libertarian Party into a big tent for libertarian socialists, Georgists, Mutualists, and anarchists and radicals of all varieties, will help achieve Karl Hess's dream; uniting American right-libertarians with their natural allies, the vehemently anti-statist, anti-war, anti-imperialist anarchists of the libertarian left. This is not a libertarian-conservative "fusionist" alliance, supporting "right-unity"; but rather a "bottom unity" alliance, supporting "pan-anarchism" (that is, panarchism), and opposing all varieties of statism, imperialism, kyriarchy, and aggression.
     Mutualism and mutualist anarchism seek a balance between socialism and free markets - or between socialism and voluntary exchange – rather than between socialism and capitalism. Mutualism can provide a much more fertile ground for agreement between socialists and free-marketers, than neoliberal capitalism or “Third Way” systems ever could.
     Notions of unity and cooperation among anarchists can also provide a balance between leftist and rightist economic systems. "Anarchy without adjectives" is the idea that all kinds of anarchists should work together, while "syncretic anarchism" is the idea that various schools of anarchist thought can be combined, united, and/or reconciled.
     As this line of thinking goes, if all anarchists agree to "live and let live" in peace, then people would be free to choose to live under any type of economic system they wish, as long as they do not aim to force their views on anyone else, nor to make anyone else foot the bill for their decisions or lifestyle. And if you can choose which type of anarchism you want to live under, it's almost as if that is a free choice you made in a market. And as long as you fully compensate whomever is providing you with physical security and legal defense, etc., for the expenses they incur, then your association with the provider(s) is use-based; and based on a fee-for-service model. There would be nothing "anti-free-market" going on in an anarchist society.
     Simply put, the Alliance of the Libertarian Left should cooperate with "anarcho-capitalists", but only with those who can identify truly voluntary participation in capitalism and socialism when they see it. That is, only those who agree to leave people alone, to assume for themselves the full costs and responsibilities of attempting to survive under revolutionary, experimental, and untested economic systems and conditions.




Thanks to Cook County L.P. Chair Justin Tucker
for the information about the early changes
to the Libertarian Party Statement of Principles



Written and Published on August 7th, 2018
Edited and Expanded on August 8th, 2018
Edited on August 9th and 13th, 2018

Links to Documentaries About Covid-19, Vaccine Hesitancy, A.Z.T., and Terrain Theory vs. Germ Theory

      Below is a list of links to documentaries regarding various topics related to Covid-19.      Topics addressed in these documentaries i...