A BLOG ABOUT INDEPENDENT POLITICS, POLITICAL ETHICS, ECONOMICS, AND ANARCHISM. Political theory, U.S. politics & election statistics, the political spectrum, constitutional law & civil liberties, civil rights & interstate commerce, taxation & monetary policy, health care & insurance law, labor law & unions, unemployment & wages, homelessness, international relations, religion, technology; alternatives to the state
Monday, September 23, 2019
Friday, September 20, 2019
A Constructive Critique of the Libertarian Party's Platform and Messaging
The following questions were written as part of the Libertarian Party of Illinois's vetting process for nominees. The answers were written on September 20th, 2019, as part of my application for the Libertarian Party's nomination for U.S. House of Representatives from Illinois's 10th Congressional District, for the election to be held on Tuesday, November 3rd, 2020.
Q:
Which
plank(s) of the Libertarian Party Platform do you agree with, and
why?
A: I agree with the party's strong desire to protect civil liberties, and to achieve decentralized/localized government. I appreciate the party's understanding of the need to balance privilege with responsibility, while distinguishing privilege from freedom. I agree that economic freedom and social freedom go hand in hand, and that the government should stay out of both our bedrooms and our finances, and refrain from discriminating against us on the basis of our membership in any group. I agree that the Non-Aggression Principle should guide our economic morality to accept exchanges which are both voluntary and mutually beneficial. I agree that a person has a right to what he produces, and that most forms of taxation take away the incentive to produce by confiscating the product. I agree that both spending and taxation by government, and social and corporate welfare, are out of control, and need to be reigned in, and so do the size and scope of government in general, the size of the federal workforce, and the pay and benefits of elected and appointed officials. I agree with the right of self-determination and the right to alter or abolish our government if it becomes destructive of our liberties.
Q: Which plank(s) of the Libertarian Party Platform do you not agree with, and why?
A: I agree with the vast majority of the planks of the L.P. platform; the only areas of disagreement I might have at the nuts-and-bolts policy level, would be cases in which some proposed reform: 1) is extremely popular, or else optional; 2) is properly constitutionally authorized through the amendment process; 3) can be done as locally as possible; and 4) has a sunset clause. A proposed law which has all of these characteristics, would likely satisfy me, as long as it is a wise and necessary law. I would be willing to propose and pass new laws, but only while repealing several outdated laws for each new one enacted. I believe that most "taxation is theft", but I also believe that the least harmful taxes are those which are minimally detrimental to productivity.
The
issues I have with the Libertarian Party relate more to some of its
messaging and rhetoric, than to its policy conclusions (which are
nearly unobjectionable; their only flaw is that a variety of
potential solutions is not articulated in each section). I consider
myself an "open-borders", "free trade"
libertarian, who supports "markets, not capitalism", and
questions whether it is necessary for government to play a role in
the recognition and protection of property claims and property
titles. This puts me somewhat at odds with the libertarians who are
more likely to describe themselves as capitalists than
free-marketers, and as strong supporters of property rights and
self-ownership.
While
I am a strong supporter of individual rights (such as bodily
autonomy, the right to keep what you create, and the freedom from
being forced to work), I do not see the rhetoric of "self-ownership"
as a helpful or necessary way of thinking about our right of
self-control, because I think it encourages us to see our bodies as
mere pieces of property. I agree with the second sentence in Section
1.1 of the L.P. platform, but I don't think "individuals own
their bodies" is either a meaningful statement, a clear
statement, or helpful messaging to get people to understand our
ideas, because some say self-ownership means the right to sell
ourselves and destroy ourselves (which I would question, on the
grounds that we didn't create ourselves). Some of the logic behind
self-ownership theory is valid, but we must avoid misinterpreting it
so as to suggest that our rights are based on how much property we
own. But as long as Libertarians continue to value "life,
liberty, and property" equally - and don't prioritize the need
to protect physical property over the need to protect innocent human
lives - then I will be with the L.P. one hundred percent.
I
should also note that, as a "markets, not capitalism"
libertarian. I would caution the Libertarian Party to avoid
designating "capitalism" as its preferred economic system,
because I believe that "free markets" is not only a more
popular term, but a distinct school of thought altogether. I agree
with those who believe that America has never had totally free
markets, not with those who believe we have free markets right now. I
take the side of the "market anarchists" (but not the
"anarcho-capitalists") in the debate between "minimal
government" and anarchism, because I believe that government is
unnecessary whenever voluntary association, direct action, mutual
aid, and mutually beneficial exchange, are practiced freely.
I
support free markets, free trade (with no treaties being necessary),
an open market system, free competition and free cooperation, and
equal liberty through equality of opportunity. But I do not believe
that being exploited, overworked, undervalued, or poisoned without
one's knowledge, are among our rights or our freedoms. That's why I
would be willing to support restrictions limiting the number of hours
which can be worked consecutively, such as in the trucking trade (but
I suspect that most LP members would have no issue with this, as long
as such restrictions are properly authorized by the law, enforced by
the most local level of government possible, and properly funded).
While some foreign nations are plagued with labor abuses, I would not
support increased tariffs, nor any other form of "economic
punishment"; because that does not solve the problem. The
solution is to unabashedly lower our own tariffs to zero, while
achieving better labor standards domestically, setting a good example
for other countries. Trade wars - and high tariffs and sales taxes -
only lead to increased politicization of trade, and eventually to
trade blocs, sanctions, embargoes, cold wars, and hot wars. The
solution to unfree trade is more free trade.
Some
Libertarians may disagree with me on some of those points, but I am
willing to engage them and entertain their ideas, while explaining
why I think it would be better for the L.P.'s and the libertarian
movement's principles and messaging strategy in the long term, if it
maximizes its potential to appeal to everyone who has traditionally
called themselves libertarians, including not only the classical
liberals, but also the anarchists of 19th century Europe, with whom
the term "libertarian" originated. I say this not as
criticism, but as a way to suggest making the Libertarian Party into
the biggest tent for libertarians possible.
Written on September 20th, 2019
Originally Published on September 20th, 2019
Edited on October 9th, 2019
Originally Published on September 20th, 2019
Edited on October 9th, 2019
Monday, September 2, 2019
Ten Reasons to Consider Bioregionalism
Bioregionalism is a set
of views regarding how our politics, culture, and ecology should be
shaped by our environment and surroundings; in particular based on
“bioregions”. Bioregional politics is the idea that governments
should make reforms which reshape government according to the
previously existing bioregions which are found in nature.
Perhaps the most
important set of reforms which bioregionalists support, have to do
with borders and boundaries. Bioregionalists suggest using to our
advantage the mountain ranges and watersheds with which nature has
already gifted us, to determine where political boundaries lie.
Mountain ranges form the
perimeters of watersheds, funneling all rain water into river valleys
and towards the sea. Basins have mountain ranges as perimeters as
well, although they do not funnel water towards the sea. Mountain
ranges and seashores already tell us a lot about where the boundaries
of these bioregions lie, and mountain ranges form natural borders,
forming a natural protection against military invasion. So why not
use mountain ranges as our borders?
Here are ten reasons why
making every watershed or bioregion into an independent nation –
and replacing all currently existing “straight line” and river
borders with mountain range and sea borders – will create a legally
simpler, more ecologically sustainable, and all around better, world.
1. SIMPLIFY BORDERS BY FOCUSING ON RIVER VALLEY POPULATIONS.
The
major civilizations around the world grew out of river valleys, and
most populations (large or small) are centered on river valleys.
River valleys – and the watersheds which bound them – just group
people together conveniently. Bioregionalism would thus lead to
increased political simplicity, in terms of where borders,
boundaries, and jurisdictions are drawn. We don't have to guess about
where the borders should be, nor do we have to suggest our own, if
they already exist.
2. SAVE MONEY, LIVES, AND EFFORT, BY AVOIDING MAKING BORDERS.
Using
mountain ranges as natural borders is more military and financially
defensible than using rivers and lines as borders, and erecting
physical borders. For one: building
walls and fences takes work, when
nature already did all the work for us
which
was necessary to create mountain ranges. When mountain ranges already
exist that we can use for free, to do any more work creating borders
would be an unnecessary waste of money, effort, labor, time, and
resources.
Mountain
ranges form a physical barrier against military invasions, while
river boundaries and “lines drawn on the ground by dead men” are
much more difficult to defend against a military attack.
Additionally, building-up physical defenses – such as walls and
fencing – would be difficult to justify if our borders were
mountains, than if our borders were to remain rivers and lines (like
they are at the U.S.-Mexico and U.S.-Canada borders today), because
the mountains already form physically huge barriers which are
difficult for militaries to penetrate.
Moreover,
it is much more dangerous and difficult to climb a mountain range
than it is to cross a river or a line on land; while people who are
looking for a better and safer life for their families are much more
likely to want to cross a
river or a line than a mountain range (which means that people coming
over a mountain range are much more likely to be attempting an invasion, than are people crossing a river or land boundary).
Also,
existing land borders are problematic for several reasons. Border
walls unnecessarily restrict the flow of labor and capital, which has
to move freely in order for trade to occur freely and without undue hindrance. Border walls are
also unpopular, expensive, and sometimes resort to eminent domain
takings. For those reasons,
using the borders nature gave us - that is, mountain ranges - is just
safer, more cost-efficient, and more labor-efficient, than making our
own.
3. REDUCE CONFLICT OVER RIVERS AND FRESH WATER.
By ending the practice
of using rivers as borders, a transition to bioregionalism will
result in reduced conflict over sources of fresh water. As long as
political and ethnic minorities are adequately represented and see
their freedoms preserved, ending river boundaries will end the need
for tribes to worry about rival tribes sneaking across the river and
attacking them, or crossing the river to gain control over it.
Reducing conflict over
rivers – and affording full and equal human rights and legal
rights, in the same political entity, to people on both sides - will
also help reduce wars, terrorism, and kidnapping of members of one
tribe by another, while increasing rates of intermarriage between
tribes. In a bioregionalist independent state, all those who live in
a river valley would be free to access it, and to control access to
that river valley.
4. SIMPLIFY & LOCALIZE ENVIRONMENTAL LAW.
Grouping people together
by river valley, can lead to increased political simplicity in terms
of environmental policy and lawsuits,
as well as in terms of borders. Water safety issues tend to affect
people on the basis of the quality of “the local water supply”.
So it only makes sense that political jurisdictions be broken down on
the basis of which water supply affects which geographical community
of people.
Nowadays,
watersheds are shared across multiple states; this state of affairs
risks allowing the federal government to intervene in too many water
pollution cases which could easily be resolved locally, within and by
a single political entity occupying an entire watershed.
Since
mountain ranges funnel all water into a single river valley, anyone
who is downstream of a water polluter will know that the tainted
water came from the same jurisdiction (and the same watershed) in which they live. This will help people whose water is being polluted, track the source of their water pollution easily, because the source of water pollution will always be someone upstream who is in the same watershed. That means
that in the vast majority of water pollution lawsuits, the plaintiff
and defendant will be based in the same political jurisdiction, thus
allowing the plaintiff to sue the defendant without creating a
situation in which the outcome of the case could potentially affect
the laws of two
political entities. That helps bypass a potential conflict of interest between states, which
only a higher authority (most likely a central government) could resolve with any finality.
Bioregionalism
will thus enable water pollution to be solved by the members of the
community whom are most directly affected by it; whether as activists, as legislators on environmental policy, or as jurors in
water pollution cases.
5.
MAKE WATERSHEDS SELF-CONTAINED & SELF-SUSTAINING
Making watersheds self-contained in terms of environmental policy and military defense over borders, while using pre-existing mountain range borders to our full advantage, will increase the chances that an independent bioregionalist state could become economically and financially self-contained.
Making watersheds self-contained in terms of environmental policy and military defense over borders, while using pre-existing mountain range borders to our full advantage, will increase the chances that an independent bioregionalist state could become economically and financially self-contained.
This
could be done several ways: 1) through enacting clean water reforms,
and then putting the state on a path to sourcing all water from
within the state; 2) through enacting reforms to putting the state on
a trajectory of becoming ecologically and financially sustainable at
the same time. This could be done through “Agenda 21” and “Green
New Deal” -type measures, which would involve “re-greening” and
retro-fitting buildings to be environmentally sustainable. This will
help ensure an equitable distribution of wealth across geography,
without threatening encroachment upon animal habitats and lands in
need of preservation.
Perhaps
fulfilling certain standards regarding environmental sustainability
and economic equity could be used as a way to justify “fast-tracking”
bioregionalist independence movements (such as Cascadia in the
Northwest United States and Southwestern Canada) and securing their
status as fully independent states.
6. NATURAL BORDERS LAST LONGER AND DON'T NEED FORTIFICATION.
Determining borders based on mountain ranges, made by nature, will result in borders lasting longer – much longer – than they do now. As it stands right now, borders exist – and change - because of political instability, military conflict, and the need to micromanage and control people.
6. NATURAL BORDERS LAST LONGER AND DON'T NEED FORTIFICATION.
Determining borders based on mountain ranges, made by nature, will result in borders lasting longer – much longer – than they do now. As it stands right now, borders exist – and change - because of political instability, military conflict, and the need to micromanage and control people.
To
resolve to permanently base all borders on natural geological
features, on the other hand – and to do it worldwide say, in the
U.N., in an international court, or via some
other method – could help guard against the risk of military
invasion, through permanently ensuring that borders will never
change.
Ensuring
that borders will never change, will especially help guard against
the risk of a violent invasion, if full rights to control one's share
of resources are afforded to any and all people who come into the
watershed peacefully. That's because guaranteeing full voting rights
and full right to access one's share of water and other resources,
will reduce the likelihood that foreigners will resort to using force
or violence in order to invade, or else resort to invading with
intentions of overthrowing the government. Doing such things would be
unnecessary to guarantee their safety, freedom, and ability to
control the resource they need to survive.
7. HELP PEOPLE AND INSTITUTIONS ATTUNE TO NATURE.
As explained above, if borders were determined by mountain ranges, then borders would last a very long time. The only problem is what to do when there earthquakes take place, which drastically change the incline of the land and change the courses of rivers.
7. HELP PEOPLE AND INSTITUTIONS ATTUNE TO NATURE.
As explained above, if borders were determined by mountain ranges, then borders would last a very long time. The only problem is what to do when there earthquakes take place, which drastically change the incline of the land and change the courses of rivers.
Fortunately,
however, earthquakes that make such significant change to the outline
of the bioregion do not come around that often. Additionally –
especially in the short term – earthquakes alter rivers' courses in
a much less drastic manner than the manner in which they change the
perimeters of bioregions (i.e., the
general location of mountain ranges and seashores).
But
whether or not we experience geological events significant enough to
affect and change borders during our own lifetimes,
adopting bioregionalism will help put us on a track to being
able to do that easily in case
we ever have to. Bioregionalism is fundamentally about making sure
that our ecology, culture, and politics follow nature's lead. “Taking
nature's lead” in terms of what we do about borders and
environmental policy is how we accomplish that, and basing borders on
mountain ranges is the first step.
But
it's not as simple as just redrawing the borders; part of that first
step has to involve planning for how to change borders in the manner
which is least likely to result in conflict and competition over
resources. Maybe when only earthquakes can change the borders, people
will not only have a respect for nature's ultimate authority over our
political affairs; maybe people will wonder whether God
Himself is telling us when we
need to change our borders.
8.
CREATE MORE OPPORTUNITIES FOR LAND REFORM.
Re-focusing politics on bioregions and the needs of the ecology, could help restore attention to the need for improvement of environmental quality (such as our air, water, and land), and to the need to ensure that land can be distributed in an equitable fashion across the country and across the world.
Re-focusing politics on bioregions and the needs of the ecology, could help restore attention to the need for improvement of environmental quality (such as our air, water, and land), and to the need to ensure that land can be distributed in an equitable fashion across the country and across the world.
Increased
interest in, and popularity of, bioregionalism, could thus lead to
increased attention to land reforms such as Land Value Taxation, and
the representation of land in legislative branches and/or electoral
processes. Land Value Taxation would reform landed property
ownership, tenancy, economic rents, land allocation, taxation,
welfare, and what to do about lands that fall into blight and
unuseability; while representing land in legislative branches or
electoral processes could help reduce the ability of elites in
government to undermine the will of the people.
The
U.S. Senate (and the 100 votes in the Electoral College which
represent it) exist because people are not supposed to be the only
thing represented in legislative branches and elections. The
Electoral College is structured the way it is – in an
anti-democratic fashion – to make presidential candidates more
likely to visit low-population states.
However,
in practice, the purpose of the Electoral College has lately been to
balance-out the voting power of high-population states by giving
power to elite superdelegates, often working in government,
who choose our electors; while
until the 17th
Amendment the purpose of the Senate was to balance-out the voting
power of high-population states by giving power to governors
who appointed senators.
Instead
of using the power of the elite to balance-out the power of large
populations, why don't we use land?
Shouldn't we be more worried about making sure that people
and the planet can co-exist,
than about making sure that elites in government, campaign
superdelegates, and elite landowners, have enough sway in
policymaking?
In
the U.S. Congress, there is a Senate and a House of Representatives.
Why not add a third house, to represent land area? Perhaps it could
be comprised of environmental scientists, climate activists,
environmental health specialists, food and agricultural scientists,
etc.. Each state could
decide independently whether those officials would be appointed or
elected.
A
house representing land area could even replace
the U.S. Senate, and probably should. Replacing the Senate with a
literal “House of
Commons” (that is, a house whose members represent not population,
but parcels of “the commons”, i.e., common
land)
would not only reduce elite power in government; it could also help
save operating costs. In particular, the entire budget of the U.S.
Senate. Environmental experts would likely opt to receive much less
than the $200,000 salaries to which senators are accustomed, so it's
possible that such a “House of Commons” could even afford to have
more than one hundred
members (which could help represent land in Congress
efficiently).
Increasing the representation of land will hopefully also result in an increased attention to the needs of ranchers and farmers in large, low-population states, to use resources (including, possibly, federal resources) to make the area habitable for population. Some farmers believe that the federal government should be paying ranchers directly to do the work that is necessary to make use of the land we have (without harming native species, of course).
Increasing influence in Congress based on land area, will help represent nature itself in the halls of Congress, while replacing the elite with nature as the only thing capable of bossing large populations around (as it should be).
Increasing the representation of land will hopefully also result in an increased attention to the needs of ranchers and farmers in large, low-population states, to use resources (including, possibly, federal resources) to make the area habitable for population. Some farmers believe that the federal government should be paying ranchers directly to do the work that is necessary to make use of the land we have (without harming native species, of course).
Increasing influence in Congress based on land area, will help represent nature itself in the halls of Congress, while replacing the elite with nature as the only thing capable of bossing large populations around (as it should be).
9.
DIMINISH FAITH IN BORDERS AND END TWO-DIMENSIONAL THINKING, AND
10. REDUCE CONFLICT OVER LAND AREA.
Adopting mountain ranges as borders, will show that river borders and land boundaries don't work nearly as well as the pre-existing borders which nature gave us. This will help reduce faith in the current set of borders, which by and large is composed of river borders that enable competition over water instead of reducing it, and of “lines on the ground, drawn on a map by dead men, to mark the places where their armies decided to stop fighting”.
10. REDUCE CONFLICT OVER LAND AREA.
Adopting mountain ranges as borders, will show that river borders and land boundaries don't work nearly as well as the pre-existing borders which nature gave us. This will help reduce faith in the current set of borders, which by and large is composed of river borders that enable competition over water instead of reducing it, and of “lines on the ground, drawn on a map by dead men, to mark the places where their armies decided to stop fighting”.
There
is enough conflict over resources in the world, without conflict
being viewed as a struggle for territory itself;
this “two-dimensional thinking” only compounds the level of
conflict and competition for resources. Nearly all
resources which are useful to
us, are three-dimensional, not two-dimensional; water, air, foods,
consumer goods, etc..
But land area is not a resource which we can consume. We can make use of land area, but monopolistic, sovereign control over two-dimensional land territory is not necessary; neither to secure one's safety, nor to subscribe to the services provided by a government.
But land area is not a resource which we can consume. We can make use of land area, but monopolistic, sovereign control over two-dimensional land territory is not necessary; neither to secure one's safety, nor to subscribe to the services provided by a government.
Suppose
that, in a small ten-story building, one family occupies each level;
and each family for some reason wants to be part of a different
political system. That is possible, as long as they are not stopped
from leaving the building by the people at the bottom floor, nor by
anyone else. As long as government employees can logistically
reach a group of people who want
to subscribe to and receive that government's services, then there is
no reason to limit such a government from doing so. There is
especially no reason
to require a
government selected by one family in that building, to force all
other families in that building to subscribe to its services (based
on the idea that if all ten families live on the same parcel of land,
they must subscribe to the same government, because statist
governments are territorial). Neither the family at the top of the
building, nor the family at the bottom, nor any government, ought to
be free to stop any household from choosing which government it wants
to be a part of. If free travel throughout the hallways, staircases,
and elevators of the building can be secured – and especially if
helipads can be set up on the roof – then there will always remain
the potential for free association between different governments and
different households at that address.
There
is no reason for governments to run based on territorial boundaries.
Granted, changing where
our statist borders are, and changing what they're based on, will not
end the territorial nature of statist government. That is to say that
it will not change the operation of the state based on the definition
“an entity capable of wielding a credible monopoly on the
legitimate use of force within a given territory”
(“territory” being the operative word).
But
fortunately, reforming our borders will
make more people question the set of borders which currently exists
right now. And we can't envision the sort of “three-dimensional
government” which I've described above, unless and until we see
that the current set of borders isn't working.
Fortunately,
since
bioregionalist reforms would likely result in adopting the kind of
simultaneous ecological and economic reforms which I outlined in #6
above, mixed-use development (a type of zoning ensuring a mix of uses
in a neighborhood) would probably become more popular and widespread.
If areas practicing mixed-use development begin to devote different
levels of buildings to different uses, then that will result in
“multi-level mixed-use zoning” or “zoning with mixed use by
level”. If that practice is successful and takes off, then in
addition to having different economic
uses
on each level, more people would be able to conceptualize what
“three-dimensional government” looks like, and communities could
foster different political
membership
by each household or level of a building.
“Three-dimensional
government”, or “spatial government”, could mean panarchist
proposals such as Functional Overlapping and Competing Jurisdictions,
and National Personal Autonomy. These systems propose creating a sort
of “government without borders”.
Another
thing that will help visualize three-dimensional government – as
well as reduce conflict and competition over land area and territory
– is “building up”. While making more efficient use of land
area is important, making more efficient use of space
is
too. The most important way to do both
of those (aside
from to actually expand
into space) is
to build up
and let people live on top of each other. “Building up instead of
building out” will help us maximize the efficiency of use of the
spaces which human settlements are already occupying, thus avoid the
need to continue expanding outwards into surrounding areas. The fewer
resources we want to devote towards the difficult process of
economizing large amounts of land (all of which we might not need),
the more we should focus on building upwards – that is, building on
top of existing structures – without
urbanizing any more land area (destroying forests and other
environments in the process).
I
urge my readers to learn about bioregionalism, bioregions, the
locations of the various watersheds and their mountain and sea
boundaries, the movement for the independence of the Cascadia
watershed, and the various bioregionalist and panarchist proposals
which could potentially result in either the drastic reform of
borders or else in their total abolition.
I
would also like to urge my readers to read my May 2013 article
“Cascadia Proposal”, which contains a map and an outline of how a
legislative body could be constructed for the bioregion. What I have
referred to above as a “House of Commons”, is called a “Council
on Natural Resources” in the “Cascadia Proposal” article. That
2013 article is available at the following link:
Written
and originally published on September 2nd, 2019
Based on notes taken on
August 31st, 2019
Subscribe to:
Posts (Atom)
Who Took Third Place in Each State?: Which Non-Major-Party Presidential Candidates Did Best in Which States in 2024?
The map below depicts which presidential candidates came in third place in the 2024 U.S. presidential election. By showing the thi...
-
To see the above image in greater detail and expand it, click on it, and open it in a new tab or window. To see a higher-q...
-
Click, and/or open in new tab or window, to enlarge Image created in September 2019 Originally Published on September 23rd, 20...
-
The following two bodies of text were written in response to a question by my former campaign manager, Phil Collins, asking me wheth...